SOURCE: Wikipedia, 2020-05-15 | Controversies
See also:
Mark Milke [formerly at Fraser Institute; co-founder of SecondStreet.org.
The notorious disinformation troll Ezra Levant once worked for the Fraser Institute, in 1995, writing "Youthquake" -- which argued for smaller government, including privatization of the Canada Pension Plan. Levant saw "youthquake" -- the term Ezra Levant used to describe what he identified as a conservative youth movement of the 1990 -- as similar to the 1960s civil rights movement except that instead of being enslaved by racism, his generation was "enslaved by debt" and, in order to liberate itself, society needed to dismantle elements such as trade unions, the minimum wage, universal health care, subsidized tuition, and public pension plans.
Society - Charitable giving & Practices - Politics - Countries - Canada - Organizations - Nonprofit organizations - Fraser Institute
The Fraser Institute is a Canadian public policy think tank and registered charity. It has been described as politically conservative and libertarian. The Fraser Institute is headquartered in Vancouver, with offices also located in Calgary, Toronto, and Montreal, and ties to a global network of 80 think-tanks through the Economic Freedom Network.
According to the 2014 Global Go To Think Tank Index Report (Think Tanks and Civil Societies Program, University of Pennsylvania), Fraser is number 23 (of 100) in the "Top Think Tanks Worldwide (non-U.S.)", number 19 (of 150) in the "Top Think Tanks Worldwide (U.S. and non-U.S.)" and number 1 (of 30) in the "Top Think Tanks in Mexico and Canada."
SOURCE: FraserInstitute.org, captured 2020-08-20 | local copy (html) | FraserInstitute.org ("Events:" more detail) | local copy ["Events;" html, captured 2020-08-20]
The Fraser Institute Founders' Award, named after founders T. Patrick Boyle and Michael A. Walker, is the Fraser Institute's highest honour. The award is presented annually to individuals in recognition of their exceptional entrepreneurial achievements, generous philanthropic endeavors and dedication to competitive markets. These individuals are role models for the next generation of entrepreneurs and leaders.
The Fraser Institute Founders' Award in Recognition of T. Patrick Boyle and Michael A. Walker has been sponsored since its inception by a grant from the Donner Canadian Foundation and by generous corporate sponsorships. Revenue generated by the tribute dinners, held to honour the selected individuals, funds Fraser Institute research and programing activities.
T. Patrick Boyle served in the Air Force Signals Corps during the Second World War and then went on to complete his business administration studies before embarking on a highly successful business career that spanned more than 25 years in the U.S. and Canada. Boyle served as MacMillan Bloedel's first worldwide corporate controller before retiring in 1977 to devote his energy to the Fraser Institute. As Founding Chairman and long-time Vice-Chairman of the Fraser Institute's Board of Trustees, Mr. Boyle played a pivotal role in ensuring that the Fraser Institute's founding principles continue to guide it to this day. [Before his death] Boyle now holds the title of "Founder & Honourary Chairman for Life." After some years of illness, Pat Boyle passed away on November 25th 2015 at the age of 97, leaving behind three children and six grandchildren. A memorial service was held for Pat at the Fraser Institute's Vancouver office on January 14th, 2016.
Dr. Michael A. Walker, Ph.D., was the executive director of the Fraser Institute from its inception in 1974 until September 2005. As an economist, he has authored or edited 45 books on economic topics. Walker's articles on technical economic subjects have appeared in professional journals in Canada, the United States and Europe, including the "Canadian Journal of Economics," the "American Economic Review," the "Journal of Finance," the "Canadian Tax Journal," "Health Management Quarterly," "Weltwertschaftliches Archiv," and "Health Affairs." Walker's primary concern as the Founding Executive Director of the Fraser Institute has been to promote the examination and use of competitive markets as a method for enhancing the lives of Canadians. Walker is the co-Founder, with Milton and Rose D. Friedman, of the Economic Freedom of the World project which is now a collaboration of institutes in 85 countries and produces the annual "Economic Freedom of the World Index." The Economic Freedom of the World Index is one of the most widely cited such measures in the current academic literature.
[ ... snip ... ]
The Fraser Institute has received funding from the Machiavellian Koch family:
[2019-09-03]: Death of David Koch a reminder of who bankrolls Canada's right.
[2018-06-23] What Does the Canadian Taxpayers Federation Get From Its Right-Wing US Partner?. Atlas Network 'has reshaped political power in country after country,' report says.
Hence, this abomination:
[2020-04-09] Fraser Institute Defends Price-Gouging Amidst COVID-19 Pandemic. The Right-Wing Think Tank Argues That the Practice Is "Socially Beneficial"
Mentioned here [2012-12]; Mapping Corporate Power In Saskatchewan
[2018-06-21] Money from wealthy right-wing ideologues helps fuel group challenging Alberta's protections for Gay-Straight Alliances (GSA) members. The Justice Centre for Constitutional Freedoms attempts to overturn the Alberta NDP Government's legislative effort to protect students who join Gay-Straight Alliances.
... The Aurea Foundation is in turn associated with the charitable foundation run by the family of Peter Munk, founder of Barrick Gold, who died earlier this year. In addition to charitable donations to universities and medical facilities, the family is known for its support of such right-wing entities as the Vancouver-based Fraser Institute. The Lotte & John Hecht Memorial Foundation and Donner Canadian Foundation are also Fraser Institute supporters.
In 2019 the Fraser Institute received a grant of $51,000 from the Donner Canadian Foundation.
According to an article published in CBC News Online, some people allege that Michael Walker helped set up the Fraser Institute after he received financial backing from forestry giant MacMillan Bloedel, largely to counter British Columbia's NDP government, then led by premier Dave Barrett.
In late 1997, the Fraser Institute set up a research program emulating the UK's Social Affairs Unit, called the Social Affairs Centre. Its founding Director was Patrick Basham. The program's funding came from Rothmans International and Philip Morris. When Rothmans was bought by British American Tobacco (BAT) in 1999, its funding ended, and in 2000 the Fraser Institute wrote to BAT asking for $50,000 per year, to be split between the Social Affairs Centre and the Centre for Risk and Regulation. The letter highlighted the Fraser Institute's 1999 publication Passive Smoke: The EPA's Betrayal of Science and Policy, "which highlighted the absence of any scientific evidence for linking cancer with second-hand smoke and received widespread media coverage both in Canada and the United States". At this time the CEO of BAT's Canadian subsidiary, Imasco, was also on the Fraser Institute's Board of Trustees. The Fraser Institute ceased disclosing its sources of corporate funding in the 1980s.
In 1999, the Fraser Institute was criticized by health professionals and scientists for sponsoring two conferences on the tobacco industry entitled Junk Science, Junk Policy? Managing Risk and Regulation and Should Government Butt Out? The Pros and Cons of Tobacco Regulation. Critics charged the Fraser Institute was associating itself with the tobacco industry's many attempts to discredit authentic scientific work.
In 2004, the Fraser Institute issued a statement of support for the legalization of cannabis and its sale on the market.
[📌 pinned article] [Steven Horwitz [Fraser Institute bio | local copy], Fraser Institute, 2020-03-27] Price Controls and Anti-gouging Laws Make Matters Worse. | local copy
Comment: The following Fraser Institute blog post provides an exemplar of neoliberal ideology. It is reproduced here, verbatim. [Refer here for additional Fraser Institute-affiliated articles advocating the benefits of inflation.]
Economists are used to having to repeat ourselves as we try to communicate the basic ideas of our discipline to a public and politicians who are resistant to our message about the importance of prices and markets. This is never more true than during natural disasters and other emergencies where real scarcities significantly drive up the prices of important goods over their pre-emergency levels. Many jurisdictions have laws that make such price increases, known as "price gouging," illegal, and they do not hesitate to prosecute those who they believe have violated those laws.
But are anti-gouging laws really socially beneficial in the way that their proponents claim?
I want to argue that they are not. And that, in fact, such laws make matters worse by preventing prices from playing their irreplaceable role as the signal and incentive that people need to both carefully ration the existing limited supply of goods and bring new supplies to the market. The best way to deal with the destruction of supplies or extraordinary increases in demand is to let prices do their job.
Before that explanation, I want to make a brief point about the term "price gouging." It's important to know that this is not an actual term in economics. It's a term used by people who believe someone is charging a price that is "too high." The problem is that there is no objective definition of what constitutes "too high" or "exorbitantly high" or any of the other vague phrases coded into anti-gouging laws. The ambiguity of the term and of the laws gives a great deal of discretionary power to politicians to decide for themselves which sellers are charging prices that are "too high." When you hear that term "price gouging," your brain should translate it as "I think that price is too high." It's nothing more than a subjective opinion. There's no objective definition of a "gouging" price.
So why should we let prices do their job? I think the easiest way to think about it is that we have a problem to solve - some number of goods have become much more scarce and we want to increase the supply of those goods as quickly as possible. This can be due to physical destruction, such as a hurricane, or due to large increases in demand, as we've seen with toilet paper during the COVID-19 pandemic. Either way, in the short run some goods are much more scarce. How do we make sure we use those wisely and get more of them?
The answer is to let prices do their job. Take bottled water as an example. If the price of a 24-pack jumps to $30 because people are buying it up or a warehouse was destroyed, what happens? People who want bottled water have some very careful decisions to make. At that price, you will buy just want you need for highly-valued purposes and no more. For example, at $30 a case, you aren't going to buy it and use it to bathe your dog. Compare that to what happens if sellers can't raise their price in the face of limited supplies or extraordinary demand. That's when people go in and buy up whatever they can find at the controlled price, and may well use some to bathe their dog, while other folks are unable to get any water at all thanks to those who bought out the supply at the legally suppressed price.
Letting the price of highly scarce goods rise forces us to use the limited supply of the good for the most important purposes. That's a socially beneficial result of letting prices and markets do their job.
However, the more important consequence of letting prices rise is that the higher price sends a signal and creates and incentive to increase the supply of the good. Those $30 cases of water are like a flare gun going off that tells people that there's a scarcity and provides them an incentive to supply more. During a natural disaster, people from unaffected areas are now more likely to buy up cases of water locally, get a truck, and transport them to the affected areas. The $30 price signal alerts them to the opportunity and provides the incentive to spend resources to get water to where it's needed.
The key here is that once those new supplies arrive at the affected area, the only way to sell them is to undersell the $30 price at the store. The people bringing in the new supplies not only provide more of the good, they begin the competitive process of pushing that price back down closer to where it was pre-disaster. Notice that letting prices and markets do their job has begun to solve the problem we identified at the start - we need more of certain goods and we'd like to have them at a lower price. Letting prices rise in the short-run both ensures wise use of existing resources and starts the process of increasing the supply, and reducing the price of the goods that became more scarce.
Two final observations about how the public reacts to letting prices do their job. First, there's the moral objection to having to pay higher prices during an emergency. Many feel disgust at those who would charge high prices and appear to take advantage of their fellow citizens. That reaction is understandable as part of our deeply embedded moral beliefs arising from having lived in a world of small groups for thousands of years before the advent of modernity and capitalism. But in reality, the choice facing us in these emergency situations is not between plentiful supply at high prices and plentiful supply at low prices. The choice is between some supply, growing over time, at high prices and no supply at low prices. Is it better for gas stations to keep their prices low and have no gas, or for them to let prices rise and have some supply for people to use carefully? The latter seems to me the more humane result, despite what our moral instincts suggest.
Second, there's the objection to entrepreneurs profiting off a crisis. It's true, of course, that those folks bringing in new supplies of bottled water will profit if they are allowed to sell them. But it's also true that the various politicians "profit" from this situation through their demagoguery and the effect it has on the support and votes they get from the public. Everyone here has their self-interest in play and everyone is trying to profit in some sense of the term. The difference is that the profit-seeking activities of entrepreneurs actually bring new supplies of the good to the citizenry. The self-interested behaviour of politicians does not change the supply of goods, and thereby does nothing to solve the problem at hand. In fact, as we've seen, it makes matters worse.
The key to understanding economics is recognizing the importance of unintended consequences. This is so clear in the case of emergency-pricing where looking only at the short-run of higher prices obscures the long-run unintended consequences of those higher prices for solving the problem of highly scarce goods. The challenge remains convincing the public, that what is too often perceived as a form of exploitation, is a necessary step in getting the water, cleaning supplies and toilet paper they want so urgently.
There's no magic wand we can wave that solves the problem of scarcity. We have to let prices and markets do their job and solve that problem over time. Price controls and anti-gouging laws just make matters worse.
North99.org, 2020-04-09] Fraser Institute Defends Price-Gouging Amidst COVID-19 Pandemic. The Right-Wing Think Tank Argues That the Practice Is "Socially Beneficial."
Return to Persagen.com